Consultants are often willing to write reports to support floundering
arguments. The forest industry's commissioning a report comparing the
assistance it receives with other industries is a case in point.
Or maybe similar to the recent Sunday
Tasmanian Op Ed piece that was riddled with errors from the very first
paragraph, designed as an educational exercise, encouraging students to spot
the incorrect facts, identify the non sequiturs and the sophist techniques with
a view to honing their skills.
Consider the following. “The rationale for
paying subsidies to move ferry passengers across Bass Strait is the
contributions the ferries make to tourism particularly along Tasmania’s north
west coast” (p8).
Then on p 52, “(t)ourism activity in Tasmania
is subsidised by both the Australian and Tasmanian Governments. The
(allocations to the) Passenger Freight Equalisation Scheme (are on the basis)
that the transport sea route should be treated in the same way as the other
major truck routes in mainland Australia”.
Confused?
The last bit suggests a persuasive reason for
ignoring the Passenger Freight Equalisation Scheme as a tourism subsidy.
But p 52 continues, “(t)he Tasmanian
Government also funds the TT Line operation and in 2006 committed $115 million
over three years to secure the Bass Strait ferry system’s future…….the average
payment per year is $38 million. This sum is included (as a subsidy) for
tourism.”
So even though it is acknowledged that Bass
Strait should be treated in the same way as the other major truck routes in
mainland Australia, the passenger subsidy and the funds to TT Line are both
included as subsidies to the tourism industry.
Bass Strait subsidies of $72 million took the
total tourism subsidies to $92 million, more than 3 times greater than that
provided to forestry (p 52).
These forestry subsidies had however been
neatly pruned.
In the matter of infrastructure assistance on
p 12 it was stated that “forestry roads bestow benefits for both public and
private industry users and the separation of these benefits is a complex task
given that roads and bridges serve multiple uses”.
But don’t the ferries bestow multiple
benefits?
Let’s not worry about inconsistencies while we
backtrack a little.
What is usually included as industry
assistance?
The starting point for almost all analyses of
industry assistance is the Productivity Commission. (PC)
Overview
of the Productivity Commission
Government assistance to industry is provided
by tariffs, budgetary outlays, taxation concessions, regulatory restrictions
and other measures.
The Productivity
Commission Act 1998 defines government assistance to industry as
“any act that, directly or indirectly, assists a person to carry on a business
or activity, or confers a pecuniary benefit on, or results in a pecuniary
benefit to, a person in respect of carrying on a business or activity”.
Assistance thus takes many forms. It extends
beyond direct government subsidies to particular firms or industries, and
includes tariffs, quotas, regulatory restrictions on imported goods and
services and tax concessions. Assistance can also arise from the provision of
services below cost by government agencies and from government procurement
policies.
Each year the PC publishes a Trade and
Assistance Review, the latest for 2007/08 issued 27th May 2009. The review
gives detailed estimates of Government assistance to industry, mainly tariff
assistance, and Federal budgetary measures including outlays and tax
concessions.
Mining and primary production industries
receive little tariff assistance on outputs, and tariffs are not levied on
services. On the other hand, because of their cost-raising effects on inputs,
tariffs impose penalties on all industries.
Outside the manufacturing sector, the forestry
and logging industries are estimated to receive net-positive tariff assistance
in 2007-08. Some imported products attract tariffs (for example softwood
conifers). All other primary, mining and service industries incur a net penalty
from the level and structure of tariffs in Australia.
The estimates do not aim to capture all
Australian Government support for industry; nor, do they include State
government assistance other than some rural support programs
Also excluded are key government measures
affecting forestry relate to resource management issues, such as the pricing of
forest products, and certain tax provisions relating to investments in
plantation forestry by managed investment schemes.
The
Graeme Wells approach
Graeme in estimating subsidies to the forestry
industry has essentially used the PC approach.
There is very little tariff assistance to the
forestry industry, a small amount to softwoods as mentioned above.
To the items of assistance detailed in PC’s
Trade and Assistance Review, Graeme has added estimates in the missing areas,
viz, additional State Government support, subsidised wood prices from FT and
tax subsidies via MISs.
The approach is a conservative orthodox
assessment of the level of assistance to the forestry industry.
The aim of an economic assessment like this is
to enable a judgement to be made as to whether the money could be better spent
elsewhere.
The
Bruce Felmingham approach
It must be said at the outset that Bruce’s aim
is not to offer a different view of the quantum of assistance to the forestry
industry per se, but rather to compare assistance to the forestry industry with
4 other industries, notably tourism and mining.
Rather than start with the PC baseline levels,
Bruce starts with a much narrower definition of industry assistance by
excluding amounts usually otherwise included.
On p12 “(t)ax concessions or other forms of
favourable tax treatment are not included because they are not necessarily paid
to the industry directly or indirectly. In some cases (they) are not designed
to facilitate the operations of an industry…… it is quite appropriate to
disregard (MISs) as a subsidy paid to industry when they benefit investors
only.”
The supporting arguments as to why it is
appropriate to disregard MIS assistance are very skimpy.
The whole MIS system prospered because it
provided a structure for investors to fund an investment in trees which in turn
were fully controlled by a MIS company, who were rewarded by receiving prepaid
fees, thus relieving them of the need to offer their own security to borrow.
It provided extra cash flow to MIS companies.
They outsourced their working capital requirements and obtained access to a
resource they controlled.
It was an unbelievable bonanza.
If an MIS investor who has borrowed say
$100,000 to lease land from a forestry company and establish a plantation, is
not part of the forestry industry, then to what industry does he/she belong?
If MIS investors are not part of the forestry
industry there is no need to consider MIS tax concession as assistance to the
forestry industry. That is Bruce’s argument.
Is not the fact that in 2007, 50% of Gunns’
profits were attributable to MIS activities of some relevance?
Not the % of turnover, remember Bruce, but the
contribution to the bottom line.
One positive aspect is that if Bruce is
correct with his implied contention that the MIS subsidies assist investors and
not the forestry industry, the forestry industry will remain unscathed from the
current fall out in the MIS industry.
Then why all the panic amongst MIS companies?
As mentioned above, forestry infrastructure
spending is also excluded as an assistance measure, as these assets have
multiple uses and it’s too difficult to separate the different uses.
Meanwhile the tourism industry was lumbered
with the full costs of maintaining links across Bass Strait.
Then import tariffs were ignored (on p 13) as
few benefits of tariff protection are felt in Tasmania.
Maybe, but what about the costs of tariff
protection?
The PC in their latest Trade and Assistance
Review found that accommodation, cafes and restaurants (which include tourism)
suffered the second highest impost caused by tariffs on their inputs, a total
of $393 million Australia wide in 2007/08.
In any comparison of assistance surely this
impost needs to be deducted from other assistance to give a net figure for
assistance to the industry.
When comparing industries especially
extractive industries like mining and forestry with a service industry like
tourism, is it not necessary to make adjustment for imputed or unpaid royalty
amounts to arrive at comparable value added amounts? And for these imputed or
unpaid amounts to be included as industry subsidies?
Bruce acknowledges the relevance of such
subsidies but then deftly sidesteps the problem because of the lack of data.
This is the point where credulity becomes a
little too stretched. FT commissioned a study by Bruce to compare assistance
across industries then refused to part with relevant data because it was
commercial in confidence.
Bruce nevertheless proceeds. He simply ignores
the subsidies resulting from the concessional wood supply price because his
client is unwilling or unable to supply details.
Doesn’t even attempt an estimate.
Is this an economic study or a PR exercise?
Once the quantum of assistance is determined
for each industry, an attempt is made to compare 5 industries, on the basis of
average assistance received over the study period relative to the value added
by each industry.
The measures are then converted to indices for
ease of explanation, a Subsidy Intensity Index (SII) and its inverse, a Bang
for Bucks Index (BB).
Dr Wadsley pointed out (Comment #18) ”the
various measures of value added are not the same.……This mish-mash is
inexcusable given that Dr Felmingham built the Tasmanian Input/Output model
(TIRO) which is designed, in part, to resolve just such issues.”
If it is true that the author is responsible
for TIRO, shouldn’t he perhaps have alerted his readers to the possibility that
Input-Output relationships change over time and the concept of an average is
bordering on the meaningless, especially if no explanations are given.
Squirrell (comment #12) was spot on with his
observation that a measure of average generates a rather useless figure. It’s
what happens at the margin that is useful to policy makers.
What is meant by this is that an average is
simply that. It doesn’t indicate if the trend is up or down. It doesn’t mean
that merely because the average indicates that $1 in subsidy produced $56 in
value added, then another $1 will lead to an increase in value added of $56.
Bruce acknowledges this but says (on p 54) the
indices provide some clear guidance for policy making pertaining to industry
support.
It may be clear to the writer but not to the
reader.
In the words of Ms Hanson, “Please explain”?
The Felmingham Report has been described as
groundbreaking by those who commissioned the Report. Either they’ve been conned
or they’re merely putting on cheery faces, happy to participate in the PR
exercise.
If it were groundbreaking Bruce would be
queuing to present the findings at a conference of his peers.
Little chance of that happening.
There is nothing particularly groundbreaking
about the study. It is not too dissimilar to all the partial multipliers that
economists calculate and politicians and spin merchants use indiscriminately.
For example, Paul Lennon’s claim the mill will
mean an extra $870 each year for every Tasmanian household. Or Bryan Green’s
claim that plantation forestry generates 2.5 jobs per 1000 hectares. Or that
the Hawk’s deal produces $15 million in economic benefits, $3.4 million of
media exposure and $1.12 million of media value.
All too often there is a complete lack of
understanding of all these measures. Cash flow is confused with profits, value
added is confused with cash flow, average measures are passed off as marginal
measures, turnover is confused with economic value, turnover %’s are used as
proxy profitability %’s, the list is endless.
Politicians and others use these measures, sometimes
in a deliberately misleading manner, sometimes in ignorance.
Paul Krugman alerted us to Voodoo Economics.
We need to remain vigilant.
No comments:
Post a Comment