Hysteria from
interest groups whenever governments announce plans to trim handouts usually
indicates an absence of suitable contra arguments. Government plans to change
the fringe benefits tax treatment of motor vehicles is a case in point.
How dare the government
contemplate reducing allowable claims for motor vehicle expenses to amounts
actually incurred in earning assessable income?
It’s
reminiscent of the outrage that accompanied the curtailing of entertainment
expenses, which critics said would destroy the restaurant industry. Before the
changes, a little imagination combined with few scruples made it possible to
categorise many social engagements as deductible entertainment events when they
were really just mutually agreed taxpayer-funded piss-ups.
Before the
introduction of FBT, non-cash employee benefits were caught by Section 26(e) of
the 1936
Tax Act. However, the two-line sub-section was more honoured in the
breach than the observance, and a whole new act, the FBT Assessment
Act, replaced it.
Rather than
pay FBT on a log-book-determined amount of private use and hence confine motor
vehicle claims to amounts actually incurred in earning assessable income, an
employer could elect to apply the statutory formula, a percentage dependent on
annual mileage, to the cost of the car in order to calculate the amount of
fringe benefit.
Following the
Henry Tax Review, the statutory formula of 20% was adopted regardless of
distances travelled. A $50,000 car now results in an annual fringe benefit of
20% or $10,000. The value of a benefit is the deemed net value to the employee
and is the first step in calculating FBT. Grossing up the benefit and then
applying the FBT rate of 46.5% results in FBT of $9,600. The employer claims a
deduction for all vehicle costs plus the FBT paid and reduces the employee’s
salary accordingly as part of a salary package. The employee receives a reduced
salary but not before effectively getting a tax deduction for otherwise private
expenses, offset in part by the FBT paid.
If business
use is low and one’s marginal tax rate is not too low, it’s worth salary
packaging in the manner described. The higher the tax rate and the amount of
private use, the greater the tax savings. The median level of tax savings generated
by a salary sacrificed car is believed to be about $3000 per annum.
Colin Brinsden
from AAP, as run in The Sydney
Morning Herald HERE, says 325,000 taxpayers will be affected
by the proposed changes. However, Robert Gottliebsen in Business Spectator HERE reckoned
"28 per cent of State and Federal public servants use this system plus one
third of teachers and police. In the private sector usage is much less --
around 21 per cent of private workers." My goodness, that’s over 1.5
million employees.
Gottliebsen
did get a bit carried away, however, claiming that "currently cars are
declared as 80 per cent for business use". Wrong -- 20% of the cost of the
car is the value of the fringe benefit, not the implied private use. The use of
the statutory formula generally implies business use is quite small, or else
the log book method would have been chosen. Cars are used to drive to and from
work and by non-working partners and other associates. Forever the clairvoyant,
Gottliebsen went on to predict "on the other side coaching classes will be
set up to help people do a good job of tax cheating via false log books"
to ensure employees weren’t worse off.
Is he serious?
Are we that dishonest? Let’s just maintain the inequity rather than give anyone
a reason to cheat?
The statutory
formula has also been interpreted by some to be a de facto way of subsidising
the local car manufacturing industry. There is no evidence the formula was
intended for that, nor has it led to more sales of domestically produced cars
rather than imported models. Let’s be frank: it increases debt-fuelled private
consumption. Why governments should encourage such behaviour is not explained.
It’s sometimes said state governments benefit from extra duties, but that
simply makes it a type of Ponzi scheme similar to the first-home buyer's grant.
The statutory
formula was intended to make it administratively simpler, but as always, as
soon as an arbitrage advantage beckons, a willing army of rent-seekers appear
to exploit the situation, in this case via novated leases whereby an employee’s
car lease obligations are assumed by the employer along with other vehicle
running costs as part of salary sacrifice.
Overlooked in
the discussion are small mum-and-dad private companies, which also use the
statutory formula although they are not as concerned with salary packaging per
se. Using cash, finance leases or loans they simply purchase vehicles for
principals and associates. In most cases there’s no limit to the number of
vehicles acquired provided they’re used by associates. It would be surprising
if there weren’t a few Beemers in the student car park at Geelong Grammar
receiving tax subsidies. It’s difficult to pinpoint the arguments for
maintaining such inequities.
The need for
log books affirming business use will curtail this latter behaviour, especially
if is mandated that cars attributed to the same employee keep concurrent log
books.
The simple
fact is a minority of taxpayers receive an advantage. The Henry Tax Review put
forward eminently reasonable principles in recommendations eight and nine that
"all forms of wages and salary for Australian resident taxpayers should be
taxable on an equivalent basis and without exception" and "fringe benefits
that are readily valued and attributable to individual employees should be
taxed in the hands of employees through the PAYG system". To date no one
has argued with those principles, least of all Opposition Leader Tony Abbott.
Misunderstanding and self-interested hysteria have again replaced reason in the
public policy debate.
(Published in Crikey)
No comments:
Post a Comment