Macrobusiness.com have just posted a crackerjack article on the misreading of the Australian government budget emergency and the errant path they have elected to follow.
"A perennial
and divisive issue in politics and economics today is the matter of public
debt. It is commonly asserted that rising public debt threatens the economy and
needs to be reined in. Governments are often portrayed as ‘irrational’ actors
when they incur a fiscal deficit, causing unnecessary inflation and interest
rates to rise by borrowing to meet the shortfall.
Private
sector lending is supposedly ‘crowded out’ by lifting the cost of money and limiting
access to a finite lending pool by government actors. A large stock of public
debt and chronic deficits are considered economically harmful, due to
increasing the interest payment burden on taxpayers. A centrepiece of the
Abbott government’s economic policy platform is its strident warnings about
growing public debt: Australia’s ‘budget emergency’.
This
specious claim remains unchallenged, for commentators are generally unfamiliar
with the long-term trends in debt and its composition. This analysis fills that
void by examining the long-term trends in public, private and external debt.
Unsurprisingly, the conclusions arrived at are diametrically opposed and differ
sharply to those stemming from the established political and economic
narrative."
A
detailed long term analysis of public, private and external debt plus an
overview follows. Read the full article by Philip Soos and Paul D Egan on Macrobusiness. The article concludes by pointing out the errors of the orthodox approach and the fallacy of the debt reduction mantra.
The
Heterodox Perspective
There is
a reason why mainstream economists ignore private debt while focusing intently
upon public debt. Neoclassical economic models assume markets operate in a
static state of equilibrium, but these models are based on a slew of
preposterous assumptions which are never met in the real world. The banking and
financial system is modelled by assuming that money, debt and banks do not exist!
The element of time is also removed, making it difficult for economists to
understand the inter-temporal allocations of debt.
This is
like an astronomer or astrophysicist building a model of our solar system
absent the sun, moon and gravity – an inadequate framework that will inevitably
produce glaring mistakes. By using a circular form of logic, private domestic
and external debts are assumed to be the outcome of rationally-derived
contracts, so the level of debt is deemed to be efficient by definition. In
contrast, public debts are considered to be managed by ‘irrational’ government
planners, who cannot make optimising decisions; a clear fallacy based on
stereotypes of the competency of financial actors within the economy.
In the
post-1970s era, neoliberal economic policy has dominated mainstream
perspectives. A major goal of government has led to an unyielding mantra that
public debts must be reduced by running surpluses where possible. The obsession
with public debt and deficits has blindsided policymakers to the rapid
accumulation of private debts. For instance, the severe mid-1970s recession was
caused largely by the collapse of the dual commercial and residential real
estate bubbles, inflated by sharply accelerating private debts, but the
economics profession failed to take notice.
Unfortunately,
this made no difference, with the 1981 Campbell Report advocating further deregulation of the
banking and financial sector. By the time of the 1997 Wallis Report,
neoclassical economists had the benefit of hindsight when examining the
mid-1970s dual commercial and housing bubbles, the 1981 Sydney housing bubble,
the 1987 stock market bubble and crash, the late 1980s dual commercial and
housing bubbles, and the lead-up to the largest stock market bubble in
Australian economic history, the Dot-Com era.
With
Australia’s economic history littered with asset bubbles, irrational
exuberance, recessions and depressions, what were the recommendations of the
Wallis Report? More financial deregulation! Mainstream economists in Australia
(and elsewhere) are wilfully blind to countervailing evidence which
demonstrates the harms caused by financial deregulation.
The
reason that financial deregulation is advocated becomes obvious: booming
private debts enhance the power, profit and authority of the horde of private
monopolists, usurers, speculators, rent seekers, free riders, financial robber
barons, control
frauds, inheritors and indolent rich.
Another
widespread economic fallacy is that government should manage debt as if it were
a household or firm. This is a false analogy as the latter cannot print money
and/or increase income at will. Governments that issue their own currency with
a central bank do not need to operate as if they are constrained like a
household or firm. Under this arrangement, a government can almost indefinitely
fund deficits without fear of bankruptcy – though whether it should is another
matter.
Interestingly,
this analogy raises a contradiction. If government were to manage its debt like
Australia’s households and businesses, then the immense private debt to GDP
ratio suggests the government should embark on a mission of out-of-control
spending and pork-barrelling to raise the public debt ratio considering how
high the ‘rational’ private ratio is. Clearly, this is not what supporters of
the analogy are advocating, even though it is a logical consequence of their
logic.
More
realistic and dynamic models of the banking and financial system suggest that a government dedicated to persistent surpluses will
eventually cause a breakdown in the economy. The reason for this is as follows.
There are three ways for income or demand to increase in a capitalist economy:
a current account surplus, a budget deficit and/or increased private sector
indebtedness. If government runs persistent surpluses in the face of CADs, then
the only way for an economy to grow is via increased private sector
indebtedness.
The
dynamics of rapid and toxic private debt accumulation caused the GFC, precisely
as the exponential rate of growth ended around 2008. The Howard government
provides an obvious example of this trend. From 1996 to 2007, ten out of twelve
annual budgets produced a surplus, while the current account remained in persistent deficit. The result: private debts ballooned,
particularly in the household and non-banking financial sectors, though more
slowly in the non-financial business sector.
While
Howard and Costello bestowed themselves with the gratuitous titles of ‘good
economic managers’, their management of debt was in fact appalling given the
exponentially-growing private debt juggernaut they presided over. This runaway
debt train continued under Swan and Hockey, indicating they are no better than
each other regarding the issue of debt. Both sides of Australian politics have
really been managing a bubble, not an economy.
A more sensible approach is for government to engage in moderate
and persistent deficits of around 3 per cent of GDP. Over time, the level of
public debt remains relatively constant to GDP as the economy becomes
progressively larger. This helps reduce reliance on increased private sector
indebtedness to grow the economy and wards off the threat that accelerating
private debt could cause further asset bubbles.
Research
indicates there is no evidence
for a specific public debt to GDP threshold that undermines economic growth.
The revelations coming out of the ‘Excelgate’ scandal have confirmed this. Unfortunately, the
prevailing belief is the opposite: in an attempt to curb rising public debt and
address falling tax revenues, politicians often implement austerity measures –
raising taxes and slashing expenditure – which worsens any economic downturn as
government and private sector demand falls in unison.
Economists
advocating austerity misguidedly use equilibrium models to assert rising
government debt will burden future generations and ‘crowd out’ private sector
borrowing, following an alleged rise in interest rates. This view should be
disregarded, as the endogenous creation of credit and the flow of causation
from loans to reserves demonstrates the private sector is not limited by the
scope of government borrowings (the falsified money multiplier model and commodity
view of money).
If bank
lending is not constrained (‘credit is created from thin air’), then it follows
the standard balance sheet model asserting a dollar lent to the government is
one less dollar available to the private sector is false. Further, significant
lending to the public sector may ‘crowd-in’ private sector investment because
the assessment of loan portfolio safety rises when it is composed of a greater
proportion of government assets, typically in the form of government bonds.
If any
crowding-out does occur, then it is the banks themselves that are to blame.
They have chosen to lend immense sums to households instead of the more
productive non-financial business sector, boosting profits from interest income
and fees off a thinly-capitalised base. The result is less credit is made
available to the non-financial business sector. Government is not forcing the
banks to take this course of action; they have done so of their own free
volition.
Reducing
the Deficit
If the
government was serious about reducing the deficit, it could be achieved in a
far more efficient and equitable manner than is currently being pursued via
cuts to social welfare and associated expenditures. Australia already has very
low social welfare spending relative to GDP, relying the most upon
income-testing and directing the greatest proportion of support to the poor,
resulting in the most efficient outcome in terms of inequality reduction per dollar
of expenditure anywhere in the OECD.
Theoretically,
the deficit could be easily plugged in an efficient and equitable manner.
Government should focus on reducing the scope of economic rents that are
privatised, estimated at a total of $340 billion or 23.6 per cent of GDP
in 2012, and slashing tax
expenditures, estimated at over 8 per cent or around $110 billion in
2010, much of it directed at superannuation, mining and housing. The $8.8 billion boost to the RBA could be reversed, which didn’t
ask for or require it.
$9.1
billion was lost to the repeal of the carbon tax, and another $4.9 billion from
cutting the corporate tax rate to 28.5 per cent. The refusal to reform taxation
onto efficient bases combined with funding of the paid parental leave policy,
roads, border security, education and the latest round of foreign adventurism
in the Middle East, are set to cost taxpayers tens of billions of dollars more.
As
Treasurer Hockey openly admitted while in New Zealand, there is no ‘budget
emergency’. The government has simply fabricated panic over the budget to ram
through unpopular measures, further skewing distributional effects to advantage
the wealthy. The hysteria surrounding public debt is provoked, amplified and
echoed by the FIRE (finance, insurance and real estate) sector, including its economists and political allies, for
several reasons:
- It
distracts the public from the threat of the massive private sector debt
boom. The diversion is understandable, for the FIRE sector has fuelled an
immensely profitable land market bubble enriching many.
- To
fabricate deceptive ‘economic Armageddon’ scenarios, advocating further
privatisation of public assets and services as a ‘solution’ to reduce
public debt. The end result is the expansion of rent-seeking private
monopolies, duopolies and oligopolies to maximise economic rent extraction
and above-normal profits.
- To
prevent government from funding infrastructure and other social concerns
in a more efficient manner, given its borrowing costs and fees are
significantly lower than that of the private sector. The difference is
economic rent, eagerly appropriated by bankers, notably via noxious
public-private partnerships.
- It
provides a pretext for austerity policies that deliberately disadvantage
middle and lower income earners: increasing individual tax rates, reducing
employees’ bargaining power and widening income disparities.
- It
ensures government has room to accumulate significant debts to fund a
future FIRE sector bailout. Wikileaks cables reveal that the IMF was
advising the Australian government in 2009 to limit its borrowing in case
it needed to bailout one or more of the Big Four banks due to their
inability to rollover short-term debts.
Conclusion
The
wastes and inefficiencies of government are well-known, expected and
predictable. In contrast, the wastes and inefficiencies of the private sector, especially the
FIRE sector, are not properly understood, are unpredictable and can quickly
cascade out of control. Policymakers and economists have provided a free pass
to the toxic and rapid growth of private sector debts, an outcome which
overwhelmingly benefits the wealthy.
There is
no intrinsic problem with public, private or external debt. All forms need to
be carefully managed to ensure efficient allocations into productive, rather
than wasteful and speculative, activity. As history and recent international
events plainly illustrate, the most dangerous form of debt is private, followed
by external, with public a distant last.
The
frenzied focus on public debt is an unfortunate distraction; an increase in
public debt and larger deficits would be welcome, given the weakness in the
economy outside of the FIRE and mining sectors, and the social returns to
public investment. Concern over historically
low public debt is misplaced, despite the claims of government, the
FIRE sector and many economists.
At
present, the public debt burden is certainly sustainable, even if interest
rates were to increase. The fashionable but unsubstantiated assertion is that
rising public debt and deficits pose a risk to the economy. Compared to the
pre-WW2 era, governments of today are a picture of fiscal responsibility and
prudence, regardless of their political persuasion.
Australia’s
history provides a test of whether a relatively high level of public debt is
damaging to the economy. Coming out of WW2, the economy experienced three
decades of sustained and equitable growth during the social democratic period.
Australia’s experience suggests high levels of public debt are not necessarily
detrimental, and the much smaller levels today are benign.
The case
against public debt and deficits are based upon pseudo-scientific economic
theory which has not progressed since the 19th century,
political point-scoring and rank opportunism. Australia certainly does not have
a ‘budget emergency’, is not ‘running out of money’, and is not headed towards
‘peak debt’ or ‘bankruptcy’. In conclusion, “Australia does have, however, a surplus of
government hypocrisy and a deficit in truthfulness and competence.”
Hi John, well written and spot on. You should publish this on Joe Hockey's Facebook page. I think it would surprise him to know others have a better handle on economic knowledge.
ReplyDelete