Assumptions
of 80 to 90 year rotations in native forests formed the basis for estimating
the future sustainable volumes that could be extracted from our public forests as
part of the forest peace process.
It
would be a pure coincidence if the sustainable rotations led to a sustainable
FT.
If
timber is sold with inadequate margins as FT does then it won’t be financially sustainable
regardless of whether the forests are sustainable.
Yet
FT claims logging a small poorly managed production forests like Lapoinya after
60 years of regrowth yielding only 245 tonnes of timber per hectare is a
profitable exercise.
It’s
only profitable if a lot of costs are ignored.
When FT personnel talk about a coupe being profitable they are
usually oblivious to the fact that from a strict accounting viewpoint, profits
now accrue each year with changes in the value of trees brought to account
Harvesting a coupe is a cash realisation exercise not a profit
making event. This is a crucial distinction which most fail to grasp.
The
following is a discussion about the subjective assumptions that underpin the
way FT values its forest estate which is the crucial determinant of whether FT
is profitable.
Perhaps
losses are even greater?
A
slightly different set of assumptions would make FT irrevocably unsustainable
as it currently operates.
In 2010 FT
adopted a new way of valuing its forest estate which is comprised of land,
roads and trees. Future expected returns are discounted back to derive a
present value which is then split between the three components. Land draws the
short straw. It is allocated a zero value. Roads are allocated their written
down value and trees end up with the balance.
Forest companies, whether government or private,
don’t all do it this way.
The suspicion is the method chosen best tarts up
the accounts, rather than forming the best basis for optimum decision making. Publicly
owned forest companies, having forests with non-production values adds another
layer of complexity.
FT’s total
estate in 2014 was worth about $170 million roughly 50:50 between roads and
trees. It’s quite bizarre, roads were valued at $85 million yet the land upon
which they were constructed was valueless.
In 2015 $18 million worth of roads were
reclassified as trees.
The split and
reclassifications involve subjective judgements.
Imagine
trying to convince a dairy farmer that whilst his farm may be worth $5 million
say, the land’s worthless; the milking shed, laneways and irrigation set-up have
a written down value of $2.5 million, which leaves a crop of perennial ryegrass
worth $2.5 million. Grass is the crop that feeds the cows to earn the income.
Surely any residual value of the dairy farm must be assigned to grass? The
result is a logical absurdity. Land has no value?
It’s one
thing to value a working forest estate on the basis of future cash flows, but
it’s a separate matter to arbitrarily split any value as FT does.
What gets
included in future cash flows becomes a salient question?
Obviously
revenue. In this case it’s the stumpage return which is sales less harvest and
cartage costs. That’s fine.
Cost
outgoings over the rotation are taken into account, forest maintenance,
overheads etc. Again no worries.
Land
rental would ordinarily be included as a cost. But because FT owns (or
controls) the land an imputed rent should instead be included.
However
the chosen valuation methodology, in theory, splits the forest estate and thereby
allocates a value to land so there is no need to include an imputed rental
figure as a forest management cost. That’s FT’s argument.
But, in
practice, land is subsequently given a zero value.
There’s a
self fulfilling odour about the argument that imputed rent needn’t be considered
because land is to be assigned a value and then a moment later giving it a zero
value.
When assessing
future net income from a perpetual asset like a forest, FT only considers the current
crop of standing timber. It ignores what happens after harvest. Establishment
costs of the current rotation are ignored as only prospective costs are
considered.
That’s ok,
but FT only offsets a few costs of the current rotation against harvest
proceeds.
Post harvest
costs such as regeneration are ignored even though most are mandatory under the
Forests Practices Code. Whilst harvest and cartage costs are deducted from
sales to calculate net revenue, the costs of roading aren’t.
It may be
the costs of roads are not included when working out future net income using
the same logic that excluded imputed land rents. Land and roads are assigned a
value as part of the forest estate so the costs do not have to be included when
assessing its value?
At least
overheads are included when assessing future net income from forests. Different
from when foresters talk about profitability.
However roading
and post harvest costs are conspicuously absent from both tree valuations and foresters’
profit calculations.
The conventional accounting approach
is that expenditure on new plantations and roads is capitalised as assets,
rather than recorded as expenses in the income statement. When assets become
impaired, an impairment charge is recorded in the income statement.
But if those assets are impaired
from day one, in other words they are a crappy lot unlikely to produce future
profits, perhaps they should be written off immediately?
That’s what the Auditor General
suggested in April 2009 in one of the earlier drafts of his Report no. 100 into
the Financial and Economic Performance of FT finally completed and tabled in
July 2011. (The AG was referring to plantations, but his argument equally
applies to regenerated native forests).
That’s what happens at Tas Rail
chaired by FT’s outgoing chairman Annells. Tas Rail spends heaps on capex each
year upgrading what it terms below rail assets which are immediately impaired
and written off as future profits are unlikely.
Roading
and regeneration costs should be offset against revenue when incurred. And in
the case of yet to be harvested coupes they should be taken into account when estimating
future management costs as part of the tree value calculation.
The tree
valuation process is much like a Net Present Value (NPV) investment appraisal
where a series of costs and income are reduced to a single NPV figure to
ascertain whether it’s positive or negative, in other words whether the
investment is profitable or not. The main difference with FT is that it doesn’t
include all the costs.
How land
is accounted for isn’t just an esoteric accounting argument. Land use is a
crucial public policy decision.
Whether it’s
native forests or plantations?
In the
case of native forests there are non production values so land arguably should
be treated differently than land with a monoculture plantation.
FT is in
the process of selling the latter so the question of the land and tree split is
important.
The sale
is likely to be a sale of trees but retention of the land pursuant to the Forests
Rights Registration Act 1990. This is essentially a rent free arrangement for
the term of the right.
FT directors
need to make it plain to Tasmanian taxpayers that they are about to sell trees
for, at best, $1,000 per hectare, trees that have cost $4 to $5,000 to
establish, and grant the buyer rent free use of the underlying land for 75
years.
One
suspects a few people might be interested to know FT is granting rent free
leases for 75 years.
What’s the
odds a potential buyer of FT’s hardwood plantations with a 75 year forestry right,
crunching the numbers, will take into account all costs (or estimates thereof)
over the 75 year period in order to assess the value of the trees, not just the
period covering the life of the current crop?
The
anticipated low offers for FT’s hardwood plantation estate will certainly, in
part, be due to the inclusion of costs beyond the current rotation whether
they’re opex amounts or whether they form part of what FT regards as capex,
roading and regeneration costs to be specific.
Wouldn’t
it make sense for FT to adopt the same approach when it values a perpetual
asset such as a forest?
For native
forest with non production values, land surely has a value? By definition, if
you’re not clearfelling, you’re acknowledging other values that are worth
something. Proceeding on the basis that land
has zero value can only lead to incorrect resource allocation decisions.
FT may
claim a coupe has value and worth logging, but it really depends on the way
it’s valued in the first place.
If you
assign nil value to land it’s easy to argue harvesting creates no losses.
Yet it’s
difficult to understand how logging native forest coupes don’t result in land
losses.
Especially
clear felling.
The valuation
methodology assumes no return on land, no $ returns on FT’s land whatsoever. If there’s surplus value from forests, assign
it to trees not land?
If you exclude a whole raft of costs including
roading and post harvest costs when calculating future returns from forests the
value will be overstated.
And then
splitting any derived value in the way FT does it is very subjective.
The value
of FT’s forest estate, the only asset in its shrinking portfolio, is based on
some questionable assumptions.
One needn’t
stray from the path of reason and reasonableness to calculate a much lower
value for trees thereby making FT irrevocably unsustainable as it currently
operates.
Does the
current approach provide the best basis for sound public policy making?
No comments:
Post a Comment